Tuesday, December 11, 2012

Salt and the Columbian State



Salt and the Columbian State is an interesting variant on the commodity history, taking a microhistory approach to examine the effects of a specific commodity trade on, in essence, a single region of Columbia centered around La Salina. It demonstrates the usefulness of using commodity records to get access to history that might not otherwise be available. On the other hand, the book also has some weaknesses. One that several people have already mentioned is the fact that it is very much a lens book using the commodity trade to look at the social interactions (one is almost tempted to say social damage) resulting from the salt monopoly in Columbia.

Another weakness is the relative lack of focus on where the salt is going. I think, judging from the text, that a significant proportion, if not the majority, of the salt manufactured in La Salina was going to feed Columbian demand. At least a portion of it was used for fattening cattle, for instance. But I think the book could have been improved by spending 10-20 pages on additional market information about salt consumption.

I think the most significant element of this book, in displaying how the salt monopoly was a manifestation and source of strength for the Columbian state is the fact that it can be written at all. La Salina is an extraordinarily small community for a book like this to be written about, and the detail that is possible is largely due to the existence of the salt monopoly and the documentation and communication surrounding it. For a town of around a thousand residents to have a significant state presence in the 19th and early 20th century seems unusual, unless that town produces a valuable resource. This in and of itself would seem to help demonstrate salt’s value.

Monday, December 10, 2012

State Controlled Commodities




            In reading Salt and the Colombian State, Rosenthal pushes to explain the formation of an economically viable political state through the monopolization of a commodity. I found this theme of the state having the main agency over the production and distribution of the commodity, obviously in this case being salt, and in many ways the labor force behind it to be interesting and something that has not been tackled fully in past readings. We have read about colonially controlled trade markets but the actual formation of a state using a commodity as its foundation has been something only touched on. The cost-control element of the economic chain for salt was also fascinating to me, as it put pressure on the labor force, while also allowing them to remain viable in their ability to survive through salt production. Though I do not regard the commodity as the center of this book, it is still important in the writing of the narrative. The salt allowed for the state to become profitable but in the same vein, exert control over the working class population. So the money being made went hand-in-hand with whoever could control the market and the production.
            The book itself however seems in a way far too narrow in my view for the argument being made. I did not feel convinced by the evidence given to believe that the Colombian state rose from its conceived weaknesses on the shoulders of a successful salt market. The perception seemed to be was the importance of the single commodity of salt, and the ability for the state to control the market was the primary element of a modern Colombia, however there was much that seemed to be left out regarding other elements of the Colombian, and world economy, which, for me, weakened Rosenthal’s overall argument. Overall, it was an interested lens on how state control over a commodity chain and the regional market system could effect politics, power, and the well-being of a state and its people.

Salt and the State

I agree with everyone else that this is definitely more of a lens book in its use of salt. In fact, salt is really not the center of the book at all. The book is about the state and its effect upon local society, which seems to be Rosenthal's main aim. I think this is an important argument for Rosenthal because he wants to go against historiography that views the state as a weak actor that did not shape Colombia. For Rosenthal, the agency lay with the state, because whether its policies were successful or not, its actions were what people reacted to either positively or negatively. Thus the monopoly the state had on salt was not necessarily a negative thing for the people. They actually revolted when the state was going to close the saltworks in La Salina because it meant they would lose their livelihood or even worse be subject to capitalist forces. Rosenthal's discussion of the term "monopoly" was especially fascinating because the people saw a monopoly as anyone who bought salt and sold it at a higher price.

I felt that Rosenthal failed to argue effectively for the importance of salt, which in a lot of ways was the foundation for his book. Rosenthal argues salt was so important because the revenues it brought the state were second only to tobacco. Moreover, salt revenue was constant, and war or international events did not cause the commodity's revenues to the state to fluctuate widely. Rosenthal argues that in the 19th century salt was of prime importance to people and was a prime commodity sought after(something we take for granted today). The problem is he does not discuss consumption and who/why/where this salt is going. Is this a mass commodity that people are demanding? Rosenthal discusses how salt was important for fattening cattle, which would lead me to believe the majority of the salt was being demanded by larger landowners or elites? I think that consumption is important here because it might tell you why the government-run monopoly started in the first place or perhaps reveal any commercial connections between the government and private interests. If this commodity chain of salt was not far-reaching, perhaps the state was limited in its capacity, and was only relevant in certain areas of the state while the rest of the territory was left to function and create more "organic" markets and commodity chain networks.

Rosenthal argues that because salt is so important to people during this time period and its revenues were high, La Salina is a worthwhile area to study. Moreover, he argues that La Salina is indicative of other regions that produced salt, and can serve as a model for the history of other regions connected to salt. This is a problem for me because we have to take Rosenthal at his word for the importance of salt to society at large because he doesn't really argue this effectively. Moreover, the population of La Salina was under 200 households. This small population might mean high variability, and I wonder how representative it was. He at one point argues that indigenous peoples did not suffer the instability of other populations that were ravaged by disease because in La Salina they were connected to the saltworks and potential material wealth it provided. With such a small population, I wonder if this had more to do with indigenous survival then did the saltworks? Or maybe any losses were quickly replaced with more laborers? Rosenthal's book is based upon convincing the reader that salt was important, so La Salina was important and through a study of La Salina we can see the importance of the state in Colombian society. Had he brought more evidence to the importance of salt to society, I think this book would have been more effective, and this is one reason why if salt should be more central to the story.


Salt and the Colombian State


After reading the Colour of Paradise, it was hard for me to make the transition to view salt as a valuable commodity in comparison to the emerald, which was the topic of the previous book.  Joshua Rosenthal discusses in his book titled Salt and the Colombian Stat the strong sense of rebuilding held by the Colombian people after the colonization.  Even though he acknowledges that the Colombians did not have a strong political figure or a revolution similar to the Mexicans, yet they were able to socially reconstruct the country.   I was not fully convinced that he gave sufficient credit or agency to the indigenous population, because he did not them as ones creating the change.  However, the author shows the indigenous people’s abilities of adjusting to multiple political and social changes. 

 One aspect that I value about commodity is the social life of the product and ways in which it relates to factors such as consumption, supply and demand.  Even though Rosenthal highlights the social changes that were created by salt in the Colombia’s period of nation building and transformation, however he does not capture the same changes that Mintz mention in his book about sugar.  I feel that Mintz better discusses the ways in which commodities did a full social restructure through consumption.  In addition, Mintz to restructure commodity like sugar moves through the social classes starting mainly with the elites.   Maybe if Rosenthal used another commodity other than salt he would make a more solid argument.  Overall the book is history-based and displays life after colonization in Columbia, but it is not a book that clearly and effectively articulated some of its arguments. 

Saturday, December 8, 2012

Salt and the Columbian State


In Salt and the Colombian State, Joshua Rosenthal analyzes the correlations between the management of salt production and the formation of the Colombian state. I agree with Ben – Rosenthal uses the administration and monopolization of salt production in Boyacá as a lens to view the creation of the Colombian state. Rosenthal makes salt and its production the center of analysis because he believes that more conventional ways of tracing state development are difficult in the case of Colombia. Colombia has no singular event that marks its beginnings as a state, its topography is widely varied creating diverse and isolated communities, and there exists a strong sense of regionalism throughout the country. This can make it difficult to see the emergence of the Colombian state. However, Rosenthal hopes that his analysis of the salt monopoly will provide a new avenue to view the Colombian state, while making his argument more concrete rather than theoretical. Rosenthal equates direct administration of the salt industry to a manifestation of the state and centralization of power. Rosenthal’s work reminded me quite a bit of Mintz. Both of their works take a lens approach, are production centered, and they argue that their studies, whether on sugar or salt, spurred significant historical developments (For Mintz, the birth of capitalism; for Rosenthal, the rise of the Colombian state).
            After reading Salt and the Colombian State, I find it very difficult to adhere to my current definition of what a commodity history should be (I wanted a commodity history to predominantly focus on a social history aspect). A commodity history can be about any product with exchange value that is placed within either a political, economic, or cultural/social analysis. This is a broader definition than I had before, and has made me reconsider which books I would include on my syllabus. For our course, I might focus on commodity histories that deal more with social history and cultural exchange (Sacred Gifts, Profane Pleasures tops my list), and title the course to reflect the new focus. I would probably retain Tastes of Paradise; Black Rice; A Perfect Red; Banana Cultures; Jungle Laboratories; and Sacred Gifts, Profane Pleasures, while I would remove some of the other books that do not have a strong social focus.

Friday, December 7, 2012

Salt and State Building


In his book, Salt and the Columbian State, author Joshua Rosenthal uses the salt monopoly established by the Columbian government in the 19th century as a lens to view state building and organization following the end of Spanish colonialism in the Americas. A story of conflict and struggle, the analysis highlights the influential role a commodity can take within society and how political goals of modernization and organization can be pushed through control and taxation of goods such as salt. The author argues that while in retrospect, state policies may have been weak or unsuccessful, they had a lasting effect on the daily lives of the people in the region and the economy as a whole. Using the salt works of La Salina as a microcosm, Rosenthal breaks down and evaluates the issues of fiscal policies and implementation and sheds light on the situation of the country during a tumultuous and changing time period.

Overall, I was most interested in how the implementation of many of the reforms and fiscal policies of the Columbian state actually decreased economic diversity and raised tensions against the state in areas such as La Salina. Following the enactment of the state monopoly on salt, indigenous residents were pushed out of La Salina and their communal lands were divided for state use. Forced to resettle on the outskirts of the town and to replace the incomes they had made in the past from producing and selling salt, the residents turned to cultivating firewood or producing ceramics, occupations that both eliminated subsistence farming in the region and barely provided necessary incomes. Therefore, while salt production in the region was a successful source of revenue for the government, it actually hurt the people of the region as it forced them out of their homes and stripped them of their livelihoods. Throughout the end of the 19th century, the anger felt by those impoverished by the changes would continually flare up, and many wars and rebellions occurred as a consequence of these tensions created by state control. Ironically, the state building techniques implemented by the government were at once developing national revenue while at the same time destroying national unity and homogeneity. For readers in the modern day, tensions rising from a basic commodity such as salt are surprising because it is readily and cheaply available. However, in the 19th century the commodity was much harder to produce and its necessity made it an important issue of contention.  

Tuesday, December 4, 2012

Emeralds

Different from other commodities that we have read about, emeralds cannot be eaten, nor do they have the ability to alter our consciousness that way caffeine, tobacco and cocaine can. Unlike cochineal, they are permanent, and don't need to be replaced, as dyed cloth so often does. Like silver, emeralds have permanence, but unlike silver, their value is much greater because of their rarity. They can't be necessarily used as cash, and their value shifts based not just on their relatively quality and rarity, but also based on the relative meaning applied to them by various groups of people.

What I liked most about this book more than anything was that it was more explicitly global in its approach. Even though our focus in this course has been Latin America, the original question of the book actually starts with the Islamic empires of the Ottomans, Safavids and Mughals (three empires that are always connected together in my head as a trio together). As Daniel mentioned in his post, we see the pathway of a truly global commodity chain, from production to consumption. We see agency of the various layers of the commodity chain as well. I was also greatly intrigued by the argument that Lane makes about the role of Europeans within the greater global network, particularly in the 1450-1750 period, discussing the fact that the Europeans are actually peripheral to the Indian Ocean world's core.