The problem with defining a commodity, as confronted both in
class last week and in the readings, seems to be primarily a problem of a
multiplicity of definitions. To begin with, as a starting point there are many
historical definitions to take in, including Marx and others, and there are
also the current definitions used in subjects such as economics. Economics
presents an especially difficult puzzle, as commodities can be used with
multiple meanings even within the discipline. The one that I personally am most
familiar with, and which shaped (shapes?) how my original definition of the
idea was formed, was of the commodity as a product with a low level of internal
division (ie, one batch from supplier A has little to differentiate it from a
batch from supplier B) and so is traded based on other factors (primarily in
bulk). These products, such as grains, coal, oil or steel, are one definition
of the term commodities. Reading the introduction to From Silver to Cocaine gives the impression that it adopts this
general definition of commodities in its focus on specific products like
silver, henequen, rubber, cacao, coca, coffee, sugar, and tobacco (Topik 10).
At the other end of the definition spectrum so far are the
definitions provided by Appadurai and Kopytoff. I actually have to disagree
with Ben: I think that Appadurai’s discussion of the nature of commodities was
extremely useful in defining what I suspect will be my future definition of the
term. Specifically, I think that the two step definition of 1: Is it something
(an object, labor, a concept) with a value that can be traded for some other
thing with a value? 2: Is its nature as something with a value (past, present,
or future) the primary element of its identity at the moment? (Appadurai 13) If
both answers are yes, it is a commodity. Both Appadurai and Kopytoff use this
sort of conditional definition that means that things are commodities only part
of the time, and can move in and out of that definition depending on social
conditions.
I also found fascinating how Appadurai turned the usual
perception of the relationship between consumption culture and
industrialization on its head. He says, essentially that material culture and
consumption of goods from areas across the world was a prerequisite of industrialized
capitalism. (Appadurai 37) This is a fascinating inversion of the usual blame
placed on industrialized production for the culture of consumption and
materialism found in the modern world.
No comments:
Post a Comment